Global warming has environmental, economic, and societal impacts. The projections of the specific timing and severity of those impacts result in a wide range of values, however. Given this, How can we pinpoint the required industrial and societal changes necessary for reducing those impacts if we cannot precisely quantify those impacts in the first place? An effective climate change policy must account for numerous scientific and socioeconomic uncertainties that are likely to substantially affect both the costs and benefits of any policy action.
Scientific Background
Climate change science is in strong agreement on several important points: While there are several unknowns concerning the specific timing and severity of climate change impacts, robust evidence supports the overall concept that the Earth is significantly warming to a dangerous level and that human activity through the release of greenhouse gases (GHGs) is primarily responsible for this effect. Examples of some potential impacts include:
·
Increased
human mortality due to extreme heat, starvation, and economic stress
· Property
damage in coastal and flood plains communities from sea level rise and greater
precipitation and storm intensity
· Increased
water insecurity due to drier conditions, greater energy demands, and rising
sea levels
· Decreased
worker productivity and increased mortality due to extreme heat
· Ecosystem
destruction and possible extinction of various species
· Decreased
regional agriculture yield due to drought
· Greater
incidence of infectious diseases due to increased range of insects and water
pollution
· Diminished
global economy due to reduced productivity and increased costs
Risk and Uncertainty
Climate change cannot be “solved”, but we can attempt to reduce its risks. Risk (in the context of climate change) is defined by the National Academies of Sciences as “a combination of the magnitude of a potential consequence of a hazard or hazards attributable to climate change and the likelihood that the consequence will occur. It may refer to physical, biological, or socioeconomic consequences.” In other words, risk refers to negative impacts of any damages multiplied by the overall likelihood of their occurrence. Risk can be described either quantitatively or qualitatively. Risk analysis includes the identification and assessment of risks (risk assessment), along with development and execution of strategies to balance the costs and benefits of reducing those risks (risk management).
Indeed, in addition to the factors we are aware of, there always may be variables that we have not even yet thought of. While uncertainties should be sufficiently acknowledged, their presence does not preclude the possibility of effective risk management.
Climate change may be more complex than other issues, but it is certainly not unique as a policy issue (environmental or otherwise) that involves substantial uncertainty. If we avoid treating opinions on climate change as merely a binary yes-or-no political purity test, perhaps risk analysis strategies could be used to reduce climate change risk in a way that will be more agreeable to the majority of the country.
Uncertainty in Climate Change
Inherent variability within a system incorporates imprecision into any model. It differs from uncertainty in the traditional sense and can be considered fully distinct in the context of climate change. For example, there is large variability in the weather patterns of Omaha, NE over the course of a month. The known range of variability for that particular time and location is part of the overall long-term climate however, so the imprecision of specific measurements is already accounted for in the climate pattern. Figure 1 demonstrates how the probability of individual weather outcomes changes as climate shifts over time.
Climate includes a wide distribution of potential daily temperatures. Although there may be temporary periods when multiyear temperatures remain stable or fall, the overall increase in warming will result in elevated average temperature and increased probability of previously rare extreme heat events.
Source: Gordon, Kate et al. “Risky Business: The Economic Risks of Climate Change in the United States - A Climate Risk Assessment for the United States.” Risky Business Project, June 2014.
The phenomenon of climate change involves numerous unknowns of differing magnitudes. Models of future global warming and associated climate impacts rely on various assumptions and estimates. Climate change analyses are therefore faced with both scientific and socioeconomic uncertainties. These analyses are extremely difficult, as climate change involves what is known as deep uncertainty, in which numerous uncertainties and conflicting individual opinions make it impossible to even fully define what factors are important. This means that there will always be a substantial
subjective component to any climate change analysis. Acknowledging and
accounting for potentially-irreducible uncertainties is necessary for
presenting an honest and accurate analysis. Some examples of these
uncertainties are below:
Scientific
|
Socioeconomic
|
Statistical
relationship between GHGs, warming, and climate impacts
|
True cost vs benefits
of different policy options
|
Accuracy of climate
models
|
Future technological
advances that could reduce costs
|
Timing and severity of
particular climate change impacts
|
Subjective importance
of the disproportional effects of climate impacts on different groups
|
Potential for rare but
catastrophic outcomes
|
Quantifying the value
of non-financial factors (e.g. the environment)
|
These factors affect scientific models of climate change and its impacts, economic projections of various policy options, and the immediacy of the need for action on climate change.
Understanding Climate Change within the Realm of Uncertainty
Deep uncertainty about the severity of impacts, the timing of their effects, specific regional differences, or the proper economic valuation of climate change does not detract from the overall evidence suggesting that climate change increases the probability of detrimental impacts. This probability only increases as warming continues. Additionally, there is not only the possibility of impacts being more mild than predicted. Unforeseen major risks may exist that have not even been accounted for in current climate models, making the actual damages much greater than estimated.
Issues of Timescales
Given both what we know, and what we don’t know, does the evidence favor policy intervention immediately, or is it better to collect more information before implementing any significant changes? The below chart includes some considerations in favor of each side:
Act Sooner
|
Wait for More Information
|
Uncertainty is unlikely to be reduced
within a reasonable timeframe and may even increase as new parameters emerge
|
If climate damage is linear over time,
greater-than-normal benefits/cost ratios are required for justifying
expedited action
|
There is a non-zero probability of
unlikely yet catastrophic impacts (“the tails” of the distribution)
|
Policies aimed at drastically reducing
emissions drastically may require or induce dramatic technological and
industrial shifts that could have significant economic effects
|
Positive feedback (such as melting ice
caps releasing more methane) will exponentially increase warming over time
|
Early investments in climate protection
without certainty concerning their benefits may represent large sunk costs
|
Certain climate impacts may be
irreversible within human timescales if not prevented
|
Applying risk analysis to climate change can help gauge both the severity and likelihood of various risks while also evaluating options for managing those risks. It is important to note however that risk determinations are probabilistic. Therefore, any policy decision may ultimately turn out to be suboptimal even if arrived at through the best available practices. Additionally, there is no magic target for emissions or other policy action. Even the best policies can only hope to reduce risk, not completely eliminate it.
Factors Influencing Risk Management Decisions
Dealing with uncertainty in any policy area usually requires at least some aspect of subjective decision making. In determining how stringent a policy should be, decision makers must consider their risk attitude – a value judgement made in the face of a risky situation. In other words, when assessment results are uncertain, how much are you willing to risk?
Climate Change Risk Management Strategies Under Uncertainty
The Congressional Budget Office lays out three potential responses for dealing with climate change: mitigation of GHGs, adaptation of human and ecological systems to an increasingly warmer climate, and continued research into climate impacts and how to minimize them. Mitigation involves actions aimed at reducing the rate of climate change through reduction of atmospheric GHG levels. Mitigation practices may take the form of promoting low and zero-carbon energy sources, improving energy efficiency, new technologies to remove GHGs from ambient air, and improved land management practices. Adaptation refers to actions taken to limit the damage to people, communities, and infrastructure from climate change impacts. The term is often used interchangeably with resiliency. Adaptation can include methods such as building protective infrastructure, providing compensation for loss, emergency planning, and promoting best practices for risk reduction. Successful risk management strategies will likely involve a mix of both mechanisms. Research could be directed towards reducing important uncertainties, developing new technologies to aid mitigation and adaptation, improving resolution of climate models down to the local/regional level, and studying risk management strategies.When calculating costs and benefits for CBA, discount rates are often required. Discount rates account for inflation, since future benefits are worth less in today’s value per dollar. Therefore, $10 spent today on a policy must provide greater than $10 in future benefits in order to be economically worthwhile. As the chart indicates, discount rate can have a very significant effect on the evaluation of relative costs and benefits. Rational arguments exist for discount rates between ~1% and 7%, based on how one interprets the potential for future investment earnings or destructive losses. This decision ties back once again to risk attitude.
CBA provides a probability distribution of outcomes, however only the average or “expected” value is typically used for analysis. It is therefore not ideal for dealing with very large uncertainties, and it does not sufficiently account for the extremes at the “tails” of the model. Despite its previous use in climate change policy analysis, it therefore may not be the ideal strategy for dealing with all of the associated uncertainties and complexities. The academic literature highlights several methodologies (OECD 2015, see summary on p. 132) for decision making and risk management under uncertainty in the context of climate change. The two major strategies are described below:
Adaptive Strategies: Adaptive strategies involve selecting policies that allow refinement over time through evaluation, monitoring, and future learning. This strategy requires the ability to identify important thresholds or “trigger points” that would prompt an update to the policy. Specific examples include:
· Iterative
Risk Assessment – A commitment to continuously updating
policy over time based on what is learned from the previous period.
· Real Options Analysis – A strategy borrowed from financial markets, real options analysis involves paying a small premium upfront to greatly reduce costs of potential future adjustment (e.g. build levee walls against expected future flooding, but with a structure easily allowing expansion of flooding exceeds expectations).
· Portfolio
Analysis – Making broad and diverse investments, ensuring that
they properly account for risk and work cohesively together to accomplish a
goal.
· Robust Decision Making – Use computer modeling to simultaneously test the effect of various model parameter changes on the outcomes of a policy decision. In addition to identifying "robust" policy decisions, it can determine which parameters have the greatest influence on the economic outcome.
Robust Decision Making (RDM) has shown its utility in real-world examples. In 2007, Congress was deciding whether to reauthorize the Terrorism Risk Insurance Act (TRIA), which was established after 9/11 to compensate private insurers for massive losses from large terrorist attacks. In determining whether the bill would be likely to net save or cost money, the RAND Corporation utilized RDM to identify the most important factors affecting the bill’s relative cost. While the Congressional Budget Office and Treasury Department provided a single-value estimate predicting that the TRIA would result in higher costs, RDM provided a more complete picture of possible outcomes that accounted for important uncertainties. Analysis found that estimated costs were heavily dependent on both the assessed likelihood of a large terrorist attack and how much compensation Congress would choose to provide for losses (Figure 2). RDM demonstrated that the TRIA would result in higher costs only under relatively unlikely scenarios (high likelihood of attack and very low compensation). This analysis aided Congress in its eventual decision to re-authorize the TRIA.
Conclusions
Figure 2. RDM Output for Deciding on TRIA Reauthorization
RDM identified that TRIA would save money under the majority of likely scenarios, with the likelihood of a terrorist attack and the compensation offered by Congress proving to be the most influential variables.
Source: Lempert, Robert J., Steven W. Popper, David Groves, Nidhi Kalra, Jordan R. Fischbach, Steven C. Bankes, Benjamin P. Bryant, et al. “Making Good Decisions Without Predictions,” 2013.
No comments:
Post a Comment
I would love to hear your comments and feedback!